Chinese "true" M1 growth still subdued

Posted on Wednesday, July 22, 2015 at 10:16AM by Registered CommenterSimon Ward | CommentsPost a Comment

The PBOC has released additional monetary data for June, allowing calculation of the “true” M1 measure monitored here. To recap, M1 is conventionally defined as currency in circulation plus demand deposits. Chinese M1, however, includes only demand deposits of corporations – a major deficiency at a time when policy is attempting to promote consumption- rather than investment-led growth. True M1 corrects this omission by adding a separate series for household demand deposits to the official M1 measure.

The six-month change in real true M1 (i.e. deflated by consumer prices) slumped in late 2014, warning of economic weakness in 2015 – see first chart. Growth has recovered but is no higher than a year ago and below that of real official M1 (and M2). The suggestion is that recent policy easing has been only partially effective and economic expansion, while reviving, will remain below par.

Corporate demand deposits, including deposits of state bodies, are rising solidly in real terms but household deposits continue to stagnate – second chart. A near-term economic pick-up based on higher corporate / state spending is unlikely to be sustained without consumer follow-through.

Greek mattress stash up to 30% of GDP

Posted on Monday, July 20, 2015 at 05:51PM by Registered CommenterSimon Ward | CommentsPost a Comment

The stock of banknotes put into circulation by the Bank of Greece rose by a further €5.3 billion in June to a record €50.5 billion – see chart. The central bank’s liability to the rest of the Eurosystem related to the supply of notes is now €22.8 billion, on top of a €107.7 billion TARGET2 deficit.

The stock of notes is equivalent to 30% of forecast GDP in 2015 and 37% of bank deposits of Eurozone residents in Greek banks at end-May. For comparison, the Eurozone-wide stock equals 10% of GDP and 9% of bank deposits.

The ECB has accommodated a huge shift in Greek liquidity preference caused by the confidence-wrecking manoeuvres of the former finance minister and associated “Grexit” fears. His claim of deliberate “liquidity asphyxiation” is surreal.

Why UK rates may peak well above 2.25%

Posted on Monday, July 20, 2015 at 03:50PM by Registered CommenterSimon Ward | CommentsPost a Comment

Bank of England Governor Mark Carney last week suggested that the MPC will consider a rise in Bank rate “around the turn of this year” and that increases will “proceed slowly ... to a level in the medium term that is perhaps about half as high as historical averages". Mr Carney claimed that the pre-crisis average level of rates when inflation was at target was around 4.5%, so "half as high" implies a "new normal" of about 2.25%. Even if he is correct, however, the tendency of rates to cycle around their normal level suggests a future peak significantly above 2.25%. The latter level, moreover, seems implausibly low.

Mr Carney’s remarks have been widely interpreted as signalling a peak level of rates no higher than 2.25%. This assumes that the MPC will be able to calibrate the timing and extent of policy tightening in order to keep actual rates in line with their recovering normal level, consistent with achieving the inflation target. Such a perfect glide path is highly unlikely to be achieved given uncertainty about the correct inflation “model”, imperfect information about the current state of the economy and “shocks”. Historically, rates have rarely, if ever, increased slowly to an extended plateau. They have, instead, tended to rise abruptly to a short-lived peak. The process of reaching the normal or equilibrium level, in other words, has involved an overshoot and correction.

There were five rate rise episodes between the start of inflation targeting in October 1992 and the onset of the financial crisis in late 2007. Bank rate peaked at 6.625%, 7.5%, 6.0%, 4.75% and 5.75%. The mean deviation from Mr Carney’s estimate of a pre-crisis equilibrium rate of 4.5% was 1.625 percentage points (pp). If the “new normal” is 2.25%, therefore, it would be reasonable to expect rates to overshoot temporarily to 3.75-4.0%.

The minimum deviation from Mr Carney’s “old normal” was 0.25 pp in 2004 but rates were subsequently reduced by only 0.25 pp before embarking on another sustained rise to 5.75%. Even in the one case when rate rises stopped around the supposed equilibrium level, therefore, a substantial further increase ensued.

Mr Carney’s estimates of old and new normals of 4.5% and 2.25% respectively, meanwhile, seem low. He claims that 4.5% was the average level of rates during the pre-crisis period when inflation was at target. In fact, inflation was exactly equal to the central objective between the start of targeting and the onset of the financial crisis, while Bank rate averaged 5.4%, not 4.5%, over this period*.

Why should the new normal be 2.25 pp below the old? Mr Carney mentions headwinds to growth and inflation from global economic weakness, sterling appreciation and fiscal tightening. Such restraints, however, are temporary – they warrant proceeding slowly with rises but do not imply that the long-run equilibrium level of rates will be lower than in the past.

The main reason for believing that the new normal is significantly lower, unmentioned by Mr Carney, is a changed relationship between bank interest rates and Bank rate since the crisis. For example, the average bank interest rate vis-à-vis households** is now 2.0 pp above Bank rate versus an average premium of only 0.3 pp in the nine years to end-2007 – see chart. This suggests that a given Bank rate now has the same impact on household economic behaviour as a level 1.7 pp higher before the crisis.

Assuming that the spread between bank interest rates and Bank rate remains at its current level, an old normal of 4.5% may, therefore, imply a new normal of about 2.75% rather than Mr Carney’s 2.25%. If the old normal was 5.4%, however, the suggested new equilibrium is about 3.75%. These estimates, of course, will increase if the spread between bank interest rates and Bank rate continues to trend lower.

*The target was initially expressed in terms of RPIX inflation, with a central objective of 2.5%, but was switched to CPI inflation at end-2003, with a 2% goal. RPIX inflation averaged 2.5% over 1994-2003 while CPI inflation averaged 2.0% over 2004-07.
**Average of lending and deposit rates.


Bank reserves / equities correlation: coincidence not causation

Posted on Thursday, July 16, 2015 at 11:41AM by Registered CommenterSimon Ward | CommentsPost a Comment

Global equities and bank reserves held at the Fed, Bank of Japan (BOJ) and ECB have trended higher since the 2008-09 crisis / recession – see first chart. This has prompted claims that central bank liquidity creation has been the key driver of markets.

The view here is that the twin upward trends are largely coincidental. There was no correlation between equities and reserves before the crisis. Liquidity availability for markets depends on the relative growth rates of the real (inflation-adjusted) money stock and output. Global real narrow money has mostly risen faster than industrial output since 2008, explaining equity gains. The relative strength of real money growth, of course, partly reflects central bank policies but is only loosely related to rising reserves.

The largest fall in equities since 2009 occurred in 2011: the MSCI All-Country World Index in US dollars suffered a 23.9% peak-to-trough decline over May-October. This followed a period in 2010 when annual growth of G7 real narrow money was beneath that of industrial output – second chart. By contrast, G3 bank reserves were rising strongly before the 2011 correction.

The G7 real money / output growth gap remains significantly positive and is unlikely to close before end-2015. G3 reserves, meanwhile, will continue to trend higher as the BOJ and ECB proceed with QE programmes – third chart. Both indicators, therefore, suggest further near-term upside for equities but “excess” money growth is more likely to warn of the next bout of weakness.

Chinese economy soft but reviving

Posted on Wednesday, July 15, 2015 at 11:07AM by Registered CommenterSimon Ward | CommentsPost a Comment

Chinese economic growth has revived modestly in line with an earlier recovery in real money expansion. The latest monetary statistics suggest further improvement, although additional June details are needed to confirm this assessment.

GDP is officially estimated to have risen by 1.7% in the second quarter, up from 1.4% in the first. Annual growth was unchanged at 7.0%, implying that the government remains exactly on track to meet its full-year forecast of about 7%.

The monthly industrial output numbers* are regarded here as a more accurate reflection of economic reality. Six-month output growth reached a six-year low of 1.8% in March but has recovered to 2.6% in June (5.3% annualised). This is still well below an average of 4.4% (9.1% annualised) over 2012-14 – see first chart.

Economic weakness in early 2015 was signalled by a contraction of real narrow money during the second half of 2014. As previously explained, narrow money is best measured by “true” M1, which adds household demand deposits to the official M1 measure. The six-month change in real true M1 bottomed in December, recovering modestly in early 2015, consistent with a revival in economic momentum around mid-year.

Headline money numbers for June suggest that the economic pick-up will be sustained, with six-month real growth of official M1 and the broader M2 measure rising further. The assessment here, however, will rely on true M1, a June reading for which is not yet available**.

Another notable feature of today’s batch of activity data was a further recovery in housing sales, which, if sustained, should lift prices and housebuilding activity during the second half, with positive implications for industrial output – second chart.

*World Bank seasonally adjusted level series.
**Household deposit data are typically released one week after the headline money numbers.