Some cautionary signals for dollar bulls

Posted on Wednesday, November 5, 2014 at 02:32PM by Registered CommenterSimon Ward | CommentsPost a Comment

“Dollar smashes through resistance as mega-rally gathers pace”, claims the title of an article on telegraph.co.uk. The dollar may be in a longer-term uptrend but its trade-weighted index is testing rather than already through important resistance, while relative economic prospects may be shifting less favourably for the US.

The first chart shows the Bank of England’s trade-weighted dollar index together with the net long position of US “non-commercial” futures market participants in dollar contracts against six other developed market currencies. Three features are noteworthy.

First, the dollar index has reversed nearly 38.2% of its entire decline between 2002 and 2011. 38.2% is an important “Fibonacci” retracement level and often acts as resistance; some technicians, indeed, argue that a change of trend is confirmed only when it is broken. Such confirmation has yet to occur: the 38.2% retracement level of 94.41 compares with a current rally high of 93.94 (on Monday)*. Note also that the Fibonacci level coincides approximately with the 2009 high of 95.08. The 94-95 area, therefore, represents a significant technical barrier.


Secondly, the rise in the dollar index from its 2011 low has occurred in five waves – three sustained upswings separated by two corrective phases. According to Elliott Wave theory, this pattern suggests a completing move that will be followed by a more significant correction than the prior two set-backs.

Thirdly, the futures market net long position is at the top of its historical range. The position reached similar extremes at the end of the prior two upswings since 2011. It was similar in magnitude but opposite in sign at the 2011 low. Futures market participants, at least, appear already to have bought in fully to the “mega-rally” story.

Technical considerations, of course, can be blown away by “fundamentals”. The consensus view is that US economic health and rising wage pressures will ensure Fed tightening in 2015, while the ECB and even the Bank of Japan will be forced to ease further in response to limp growth and deflation risks. Monetary trends, however, question this scenario: six-month growth of real narrow money is solid and rising in the Eurozone and is recovering in Japan but has fallen in the US since mid-2014 – second chart**. US economic growth may disappoint (again) in 2015 while the Eurozone / Japan could outperform current low expectations.


 
*Any break needs to be sustained for several days to be considered valid.
**The chart includes October estimates for the US and Japan.


Japanese QE may remain ineffective without reserves rate cut

Posted on Monday, November 3, 2014 at 03:21PM by Registered CommenterSimon Ward | CommentsPost a Comment

The Bank of Japan (BoJ) has expanded QE to include equities using the Government Pension Investment Fund (GPIF) as a conduit. The BoJ will raise its rate of Japanese government bond (JGB) purchases by ¥30 trillion per annum, financed partly by creating more bank reserves. It will buy most of these securities from the GPIF, which plans to sell about ¥25 trillion of domestic bonds to reduce its portfolio allocation from 55% at end-June to a new target of 35%. The GPIF will use the cash received from the BoJ to buy about ¥20 trillion of domestic and foreign equities to reach new target allocations of 25% each, up from 18% and 16% respectively at end-June. With the BoJ planning to plough an additional ¥2 trillion into equity exchange-traded funds, the net impact is that the Japanese official sector (i.e. BoJ and GPIF combined) will remove about ¥11 trillion or $100 billion each of domestic and foreign equities from circulation, paying for these mainly by creating reserves. The combined ¥22 trillion or $200 billion is equivalent to 4.5% of Japanese annual GDP or 0.5% of the market capitalisation of the MSCI All Country World index.

The expansion of QE will extend the divergence between the balance sheet sizes of the BoJ and other major central banks. The BoJ’s assets are on course to rise from 57% of GDP now to more than 75% by end-2015. This compares with 26% for the Federal Reserve, 21% for the European Central Bank (ECB) and 23%* for the Bank of England currently – see first chart. (The BoJ, however, is some way from overtaking the Swiss National Bank, with assets of 82% of GDP.)

   
Japan’s new QE-equities (QEE) policy has boosted markets but will it prove any more effective than bond purchases in generating nominal economic expansion? Success is judged here to depend on whether the new policy lifts monetary growth. As previously explained, Japanese QE to date has had a negligible monetary impact because 1) the increase in bank reserves has caused banks to cut their JGB holdings, offsetting the effect of the BoJ’s purchases, and 2) an expected weakening of the yen has caused an outflow of money to other countries. Both “leakages” should continue under QEE.

The popular view is that BoJ policy easing has been more radical than that of the ECB, implying a greater chance of success. This is questionable. Japanese bank reserves are ballooning, in contrast to a fall in the Eurozone, but banks are not using this liquidity to expand their lending or investments, partly because the BoJ continues to pay a 0.1% interest rate on excess reserve balances. The BoJ, in this respect, has followed the Fed and Bank of England; the ECB, by contrast, is penalising banks for holding excess reserves, via its -0.2% deposit rate – second chart. The BoJ, in other words, is focusing on the quantity of reserves while the ECB is targeting their velocity of circulation. It remains to be seen which approach is more effective, although Eurozone money measures have risen sharply since a negative deposit rate was imposed in June – see previous post.

The 5-4 split on the BoJ’s Policy Board suggests that QEE represents the last throw of the monetary dice for Governor Kuroda. Has he misjudged by choosing to use his remaining capital to expand QE rather than cut the reserves rate?

 



*September estimate: no update will be available until late 2015 because of the Bank of England’s decision to end timely reporting of its assets – see previous post.

UK money trends suggesting steady growth

Posted on Wednesday, October 29, 2014 at 02:58PM by Registered CommenterSimon Ward | CommentsPost a Comment

UK monetary trends remain solid, casting doubt on forecasts of an imminent economic slowdown – the consensus projection is for GDP growth to fall from 3.1% in 2014 to 2.6% in 2015, according to the Treasury’s monthly survey.

The preferred narrow and broad aggregates here are M1 and M4 excluding financial sector deposits*. Six-month growth of real non-financial M1 has moderated since end-2013 but remains strong by historical standards. Real non-financial M4 expansion returned to the top of its recent range last month – see first chart.

The second chart shows a breakdown of real non-financial M1 growth between households and private non-financial corporations (PNFCs). Real PNFC M1, in particular, has given good forecasting signals in recent years: for example, its six-month change turned negative in late 2007 ahead of the 2008-09 recession and dropped sharply in 2010 ahead of the 2011-12 “double dip” scare. Growth has rebounded after a modest decline in early 2014, suggesting solid prospects for business investment and hiring.

*Financial sector deposits are volatile and contain less information about near-term economic prospects.

Why UK monetary policy is still loosening

Posted on Wednesday, October 29, 2014 at 09:23AM by Registered CommenterSimon Ward | CommentsPost a Comment

UK Bank rate has remained extraordinarily low for more than five years for two fundamental reasons. First, sustained loose monetary policy has been needed to offset various drags on economic growth. Secondly, the spread between commercial bank interest rates and Bank rate has been much wider than in the past, requiring the latter to be set much lower to achieve a given policy stance.

The second reason is usually ignored in policy discussions but is as important as the first for assessing whether a change is needed. As banks return to financial health, the spread between their interest rates and Bank rate is falling. By keeping Bank rate unchanged, the MPC has acceded to an effective further loosening of monetary policy.

The first chart compares the average commercial bank interest rate vis-à-vis households* with Bank rate. This average rate has fallen by 0.4 percentage points since end-2012. It is reasonable to argue that the policy stance was sufficiently loose at end-2012, since economic growth in 2013-14 has been strongly above trend. On this view, the MPC should have raised Bank rate to keep the average commercial bank rate stable and avoid unwarranted further stimulus.

The second chart makes the same point in a different way. The red line shows a “pre-crisis equivalent” Bank rate – an estimate of the level that would have been required before 2009 to produce the observed commercial bank interest rate, based on the pre-crisis average spread. This equivalent rate was stable at 2.6-2.7% over 2010-12  but has since fallen to 2.2%. The MPC, arguably, should have raised Bank rate to prevent this decline.

Put aside the discussion about whether it is time to begin scaling back monetary stimulus. The relevant question for the MPC’s doves is why they believe the policy stance now should be even looser than at end-2012.
 
*Average of lending and deposit rates, calculated from Bank of England interest rate and volume data for different types of business.

Eurozone money trends also signalling improving outlook

Posted on Monday, October 27, 2014 at 03:48PM by Registered CommenterSimon Ward | CommentsPost a Comment

Eurozone money measures grew solidly again in September, suggesting improving economic prospects and initial success for the ECB’s recent easing measures.

Narrow money M1 has risen by 2.5%, or 10.3% annualised, since June, when the ECB cut its main refinancing and deposit rates by 10 basis points (bp), the latter to a negative level. Broad money M3 has increased by 1.3%, or 5.4% annualised, over the same period. The ECB lowered rates by a further 10 bp in September.

The monetary pick-up casts strong doubt on the IMF’s recent estimate of a 40% chance of a recession by mid-2015. The six-month change in real (i.e inflation-adjusted) M1 turned negative ahead of the 2008-09 and 2011-12 recessions; it is currently the strongest since late 2012, ahead of the 2013 economic recovery – see first chart.

Six-month real M3 growth, meanwhile, is the highest since 2009. (Real M3, however, is less reliable than M1 as a leading indicator, failing, for example, to signal the 2008-09 recession in advance.)

Stronger real money trends reflect a rise in nominal expansion rather than lower inflation. The six-month change in consumer prices, seasonally adjusted, has recovered since the spring, though remains weak – second chart.

Monetary acceleration undermines the popular narrative that the ECB is “behind the curve” and must embrace full QE including sovereign bond purchases to head off deflation. The ECB’s rate cuts, indeed, appear to have been more effective in stimulating monetary growth than the Bank of Japan’s ultra-aggressive QE programme. As previously discussed, Japanese QE has, until recently, involved commercial banks swapping bonds for central bank reserves, with no impact on the money holdings of households and non-financial firms. Japanese M3 rose by 3.2% annualised in the three months to September versus 5.4% growth in the Eurozone.

The ECB publishes a country breakdown of overnight deposits, comprising about 80% of Eurozone M1. Six-month real deposit growth remains higher in the periphery than the core, suggesting superior economic and equity market prospects – third chart. Trends are strongest in Portugal and Spain but Italy is outperforming Germany and France – fourth chart.